Discussion Questions PUBLIC OPINION AND THE CLASSICAL TRADITION (Thursday, January 20)
1. What does Walter Lippmann (1922) mean when he
refers to the pictures in our heads? Who
creates these pictures? Why are they so
influential?
2. On the first page of his essay,
James Bryce (1900) asks a deceptively simple question: "What do we mean by public
opinion?" What answer does he give? Why is there confusion over the definition?
3. Bryce understands the nature of public
opinion by looking at the way it percolates throughout society. It is something that grows
and spreads, but also something that is made and manipulated. What four stages in its
development does he identify?
4. According to Bryce, how much of the
"average man's" views are "really of his own making"? What role do the
"makers or leaders of opinion" play?
5. How does Bryce characterize the
political and social beliefs of "nineteen persons out of very twenty"? Is his
description fair?
6. Lowell (1913) says: "There is a
common impression that public opinion depends upon and is measured by the mere number of
persons to be found on each side of a question; but this is far from accurate." What,
then, is it? Is unanimity required? A majority?
7. Lowell believes that "the ideas
of people who possess the greatest knowledge of a subject are also of more weight than
those of an equal number of ignorant persons." Is/should this be the case?
Does/should "one man who holds his belief tenaciously count for as much as several
men who hold theirs weakly?"
8. Finally, in comparison to Bryce and
Lowell, how do Erikson and Tedin (2007) define the term "public opinion"? What
do they mean when they say that "public opinion and the results of public opinion
polls are not necessarily the same thing?" Do you agree?
CHANGING CONCEPTIONS OF PUBLIC OPINION (Tuesday, January 25)
1. Blumer (1948) criticizes pollsters for being so wedded to their
technique and so preoccupied with the improvement of their technique that they shunt aside
the vital question of whether their technique is suited to the study of what they are
ostensibly seeking to study. Is this a fair criticism of polling today? Does public
opinion consist merely of what public opinion polls poll?
2. According to Blumer, what obvious and commonplace
characteristics of public opinion do pollsters routinely ignore?
3. Blumer believes that polls treat public opinion and its place in
society in a way that is markedly unrealistic. Explain what he means.
4. How does Converse (1987) respond to Blumers criticism? Why,
according to Converse, is the pollsters view of public opinion better than
Blumers antiquarian view? Do you agree?
5. Where does Berinskys (1999) work fit in to the Blumer vs.
Converse debate?
6. Berinsky says that under some circumstances, opinion polls may
poorly reflect collective public sentiment
Why? What examples does he give?
What are the consequences?
A PRIMER ON SURVEY RESEARCH (Thursday, January 27)
1. According to Zaller and Feldman (1992), what are
attitudes and how well do surveys measure them?
2. What, in contrast, are non-attitudes?
3. Zaller and Feldman argue that opinion research is beset by two
major types of artificial variance. What are they?
4. What three axioms are introduced by Zaller and Feldman?
5. For those who work in the field of survey research, what are the
consequences of Zaller and Feldmans work?
6. In Ashers book, Polling and the Public: What Every Citizen
Should Know (2004), he stresses the importance of question wording, and even the order
question in which questions are asked? Why? How does this connect to Zaller and
Feldmans article?
7. With both reading assignments in mind, how easily can attitudes be
manipulated within a survey? Can you think of any examples? Is it possible to reveal
someones true attitudes?
THE USE (AND ABUSE) OF POLLS (Tuesday, February 1)
1. How are public opinion polls used, and by whom? Are polls used for
different purposes by different groups?
2. What standards has the American Association for Public Opinion
Research adopted for reporting polls results? According to Asher (2004), how effective are
they?
3. When it comes to election polls, there are many varieties. Can you
name them?
4. Why are some election predictions so far off (e.g., the recent New
Hampshire primary)?
5. Asher believes that the media is often careless and irresponsible
when interpreting poll results. What are some examples?
6. According to Asher, what questions should we keep in mind when
evaluating polls?
BEYOND NUMBERS: THE QUANTITATIVE-QUALITATIVE DEBATE (Thursday, February 3)
1. What is Hochschild's (1981) book about? What question is she trying
to address?
2. Describe the methodology she uses. How does it differ from standard
survey research?
3. Hochschild makes four claims about the value of intensive
interviewing, ranging from (in her words) the "cautious" to the
"bold." What are they? Does she make a convincing case?
4. Hochschild argues that people apply different distributive norms to
different domains, or spheres, of life. Describe what she means.
5. Compare Hochschild's work to Feldman and Zaller (1992). Does she
really generate results that survey research cannot? Is the approach used by the latter a
fair compromise between two extremes?
6. We tend to prefer modern polls because they are more representative,
but as Hochschild demonstrates, we also lose something along the way-a sense of true
deliberation, perhaps. Fishkin and Luskin (2005) argue that modern polls are
"cognitively threadbare." How does their technique of "deliberative
polling" attempt to redress that?
AGENTS OF SOCIALIZATION (Tuesday, February 8)
1. What is political socialization?
2. What are the primary agents of socialization (e.g., family, school,
peer groups, etc.)? Which of these is most powerful?
3. When does political awareness begin? How important is early
learning? What impact does it have on later life?
4. According to Niemi and Hepburn (1995), what exaggerated
premises and misunderstood research findings led to the demise of
research on political socialization?
5. What is the primacy principle? Are its assumptions
accurate? If not, what forces cause adults to reconsider their positions?
6. Niemi and Hepburn write that partisanship is relatively stable,
but there is certainly no justification for capturing it at its earliest manifestation and
assuming that it will persist through adulthood. Is this statement consistent with
your own life experience?
7. Niemi and Hepburn say that the high school years should perhaps
hold the greatest interest for us because it is then that society makes the most explicit
and concentrated effort to teach political knowledge and civic values. Consider
Litts (1963) findings on this point. In his opinion, how well do schools socialize
students?
8. What advice do Niemi and Hepburn give for reestablishing
political socialization as a viable and vibrant field of study?
POLITICAL KNOWLEDGE (Thursday, February 10)
1. In an excerpt from The Phantom Public, Walter Lippmann writes:
The private citizen today has come to feel rather like a deaf spectator in the back
row, who ought to keep his mind on the mystery off there, but cannot quite manage to keep
awake. Is this a accurate judgment, even if it is harsh? In spite of it, why is
Lippmann sympathetic? What does he believe to be an unattainable ideal?
2. According to Carpini and Keeter
(1993), what should people know about politics? Are national civics testsfrequently
given to and failed by college studentsa valid indicator, or does political
knowledge require more than bits of information?
3. Kuklinski, et al. (2000) argue that
To be informed requires, first, that people have factual beliefs and, second, that
those beliefs be accurate. What do they believe are the consequences of being
uninformed? What about misinformed? Which is worse and why?
4. Kuklinski, et al. expect that people will hold factual beliefs
about public policy, but that many will hold inaccurate ones and hold them
confidently. Aside from the authors example on welfare, can you think of any
examples (e.g., Iraq and WMD)?
5. What happens when educators give citizens correct facts? Do policy
preferences adjust accordingly?
ANXIETY AND EMOTION (Tuesday, February 15)
1. As Brader (2005) tells us, emotional language is powerful when
invoked in political advertising. There is a tendency, however, to see decision-making
based on affect as badinferior, irrational, superficial, even destructive. Is this a
fair criticism? Are decisions routed through the cognitive centers of our brains always
better? Why or why not?
2. According to Huddy, et al. (2005), when it comes to managing the
publics reaction to terrorism, the government faces quite a challenge. In order to
secure support for their policies, leaders must make people aware of the threat without
unduly scaring them. How does this conclusion square with the Bush administrations
overall strategy in the war on terror? How might we apply the same logic to an issue like
global warming?
SOCIAL IDENTITIES (Thursday, February 17)
In a classic book, simply titled Voting, Lazarsfeld, Berelson and Gaudet (1948) concluded
that a person thinks, politically, as he is socially. Social characteristics
determine political preferences. In tomorrows class, we will consider two of
those characteristics in detail: political partisanship and race.
1. Green, et al. (2002) argue that the term identification is
commonly used in two ways. One meaning suggests affinity, the other
self-categorization. In a practical sense, what do these terms mean?
2. According to the authors, where does political partisanship fit in?
Are citizens justified in thinking of themselves as Democrats or Republicans if they do
not vote like a partisan, or think like a partisan, or register as a
partisan
?
3. Green, et al. say that the distinctions they make may seem like
splitting hairs, but a number of important empirical insights grow out of them. What
are they?
4. If self-described partisans harbor genuine attachments to
partisan groups, how influential is this likely to be on public opinion and
political behavior?
5. According to Kinder and Winter (2001), why do the views of blacks and
whites differ so markedly? They offer four alternative and quite general ways that
the racial divide in opinion might be understood. What are they?
6. Kinder and Winter argue that the differences in opinion between
whites and blacks is huge. For instance, where as 89.2 percent of
African Americans in 1992 supported the idea that the government in Washington should see
to it that black people get fair treatment in jobs, just 48.7 percent of whites did
so. Is this a function of group interest or, perhaps, self-interest? What role does
in-group solidarity and/or out-group resentment play?
SELF-INTEREST (Tuesday, February 22)
1. According to Brewer (2001), what, exactly, is the Puff Daddy
theory of presidential elections? Are presidential elections all about the
Benjamins?
2. What is sociotropic voting? What about pocketbook
voting? When it comes to economic issues, do voters tend to think
prospectively or retrospectively? Of these four variants, which
combination occurs most frequently in presidential campaigns?
3. Erikson (1989) demonstrates a strong relationship between economic
conditions and the presidential vote. What variables does he include in his equation? Are
they sufficient?
4. If the vote is determined almost entirely by the amount of
prosperity that the incumbent party delivers (evaluations of the candidates
personal qualities aside), why did models of economic voting misread the 2000 presidential
election?
5. In what others ways might self-interest manifest itself in political
attitudes and behavior? Can voters also be altruistic? Under what conditions?
THE NEWS MEDIA, Part 1 (Thursday, February 24)
As Walter Lippmann argued 70 years ago, our opinions and behavior are responses not
to the world itself but to our perceptions of that world. It is the pictures in our
heads that shape our feelings and actions, and these pictures only imperfectly
reflect the world that surrounds us (Gilens, pp. 515-516).
Our goal today is to use the assigned reading to understand better the role that the media
play in shaping (even altering) those perceptions.
1. Gilens begins with two important observations about race and poverty.
What are they?
2. What methods does he use to study the
issue?
3. What does he find? What are his
conclusions?
4. Are you persuaded by his choice of
methodology? Is it appropriate and fair? Can you think of a better approach?
5. Do you agree with the conclusions he
draws from the evidence? Are there alternative explanations? Could peoples
misperception of race and poverty come from another source? Could the direction of
causality be reversed?
6. If you believe Gilens, why do you
think the media misrepresent the poor? Are their actions accidental or purposeful?
7. Why does it matter if average
Americans misunderstand poverty? What are consequences, political and otherwise?
8. Like Gilens, Hetherington starts off
with several simple observations. What are they?
9. What is his hypothesis?
10. Hetherington uses two important
terms: priming and framing. What do they mean?
11. In contrast to Gilens, what
methodology does Hetherington choose?
12. Hetherington says that coverage
of the economy was almost exclusively negative in tone and content in 1992. Does he
provide enough evidence of this?
13. What are his conclusions and are you
persuaded by them? Think about these questions: Are there any alternative explanations? Is
1992 a unique case? Is there a difference between statistical significance and
practical significance? In the end, does he demonstrate a liberal bias in the
media, or merely a bias toward controversy and negative news?
THE NEWS MEDIA, Part 2 (Tuesday, March 1)
1. According to Zaller, the publics initial response to the Monica
Lewinsky scandal was puzzling. Why? What happened?
2. Zaller considers several different
explanations for the unusual pattern he observes? What are they?
3. In the end, Zaller believes that the
Lewinsky scandal represented the triumph of political substance over the
antics of media politics. What does he mean when he uses those terms?
4. Do you find his argument credible? Are
there any other (competing) explanations?
5. In Kull, Ramsay and Lewis
article on public opinion and the Iraq War, on what specific misperceptions do
they focus? There are three. Can you name them?
6. According to the evidence they
present, how common were these misperceptions?
7. How to these
misperceptions relate to support for the war in Iraq?
8. According to the authors, where do
these misperceptions come from? From the Bush administrations own false
statements? From the news media? If the latter, from which news outlet(s), in particular?
Is there a liberal/conservative bias here? Why or why not?
9. How persuaded are you by their
results? As in Zallers case, are there any alternative explanations here for the
turnaround in public opinion once the war in Iraq began? (Hint: There are many! Can you
spot them?)
10. To some extent, say the
authors, this period [in the aftermath of 9/11] may be regarded as unique. Is
it? How does this compare to the other cases we have discussed so far - Gilens on race and
poverty, Hetherington on the 1992 economy, Zaller on the Lewinsky scandal? What powers of
persuasion does the media possess? What limitations are imposed on that power?
THE NATURE OF MASS BELIEF SYSTEMS (Tuesday, March 15)
1. Some of the material in Chapter 3 of Erikson and Tedin will sound
familiar, reinforcing our previous discussions on political knowledge, for instance. Pay
particular attention here to what they call opinion consistency. Now that we
have explored what public opinion is, and how attitudes form, we will tackle the matter of
how attitudes are organized (or, in some cases, disorganized). Should we expect attitudes
to remain stable, across issues and even over time? If so, what serves as the central
anchor, or binding agent? For years, scholars assumed (read: hoped) that ideology would
serve that purpose, whereby our commitment to liberal or conservative principles would
provide the framework on which would base our opinions on issues as diverse as welfare
reform, the environment, abortion, and the budget deficit. According to Erikson and
Tedins review of the literature, how likely is this?
2. Both of the remaining
articlesPeffley and Hurwitz (1985) and Prothro and Grigg (1960) explore attitude
constraint in greater detail. Rather than looking at consistency across issues (what we
might call horizontal constraint), they examine consistency between abstract
principles and the application of those principles to specific situations (think of this
as vertical constraint). Which do you think is more important and why?
3. According to Peffley and Hurwitz
(1985), are citizens capable of abstract ideological thought? While the models they use
are complex, focus on Figures 1 and 2, which provide a nice graphical representation of
their work. Keep in mind, higher numbers indicate more consistency.
4. Prothro and Grigg (1960) explore the
same notion of constraint, but they test a different anchor, or organizing principle.
Instead of ideology, what is it?
5. In Prothro and Griggs piece,
what abstract principles and specific principles do they examine?
Are these appropriate choices?
6. What do Prothro and Grigg (1960) find?
Is there consensus on democratic principles? What about on the application of those
principles to specific situations? What happens to cause consensus to break down? How do
we explain it? Is this just another case of ambivalence (as per Hochschild)?
7. In what ways are the conclusions
reached by Peffley and Hurwitz (1985) and Prothro and Griff (1960) similar? In what ways
are they different?
8. We often use measures of opinion
consistency (or constraint) as a standard for judging the political competence
and sophistication of the public? Is this a fair? Why or why not? Think about why attitude
constraint matter. Should we really prefer citizenseven leaderswho have rigid
and highly consistent beliefs? Doesnt flexibility in politics matter too?
CORE VALUES AND BELIEFS (Thursday, March 17)
1. If most people fail to structure their
beliefs ideologically, what is left? How well do core beliefs, like those used
by Feldman, work?
2. Does Feldmans model presume too
much effort, too much information? He argues that It should not require a high
degree of political sophistication for people to absorb the political norms of society
when they are so ingrained in the political and social life of the nation (p. 418).
Do you agree?
3. What three core beliefs
does Feldman examine? Describe them. Does that change your answer to #2 above? Are his
conclusions sensible?
4. Based on our reading of Feldman (as
well as Prothro and Grigg), lets take our understanding of core democratic values,
in all its permutations, out for a spin. Core suggests something fundamental,
solid, stable. What do Davis and Silver find? Is that the case with the civil liberties
issues they examine within the context of 9/11? What implication does their work have for
our understanding of attitude constraint?
5. Finally, if we come to understand the
importance of a shared consensus on core democratic values, we should also consider how
those values are absorbed. Litts earlier study of civic education in Boston told us
that schools play a vital role in the socialization of young citizens. Murphys piece
demonstrates just how controversial that can be. He believes that the attempt to
inculcate civic values in our schools is at best ineffective and often undermines the
intrinsic moral purpose of schooling. Do you agree or disagree? Why? Should schools
try to make us good citizens. If not. if schools were to follow his advice and
avoid civic education altogether, what would happen? Where and how would those
core democratic values (so central to the other works we read) be transmitted?
ONE STATE, TWO STATE, RED STATE, BLUE STATE (Tuesday, March 22)
1. In looking at a series of recent elections, Barone (2001) says that
if we round off the results, we see essentially the same number over and over
again. In The 49 Percent Nation, we seem to be evenly divided down the middle,
into what pundits have called Red states and Blue states. On what
basis do these states differ?
2. According to Barone, is the country (gradually) becoming more
Red or more Blue? Do you agree or disagree with the logic behind
that conclusion? Why?
3. As Fiorina (2006) points out, even if voters in the U.S. are evenly
divided, it need not mean that they are deeply divided, despite the popularity of that
claim in the news media. When compared to Barones work, he offers a contrary
thesis. What is it? Are claims of a culture war simple exaggeration and
sheer nonsense? On what misperceptions of American elections does he believe
it is based?
4. On the subject of closely and deeply divided versus
closely but not deeply divided (see Figure 2.1 on page 13), what difference
does it make?
WHAT MOVES PUBLIC OPINION? (Thursday, March 24)
Americans are a stubborn lot. As we have seen so far this term, people tend to hold onto
their beliefs tenaciously, even when those beliefs are based on inaccurate information.
Still, public opinion does move. Change is sometimes swift, but more often slow; sometimes
unexpected, but usually explicable. Our task in tomorrows class is to reach a better
understanding of how and why public opinion changes over time.
1. According to Page and Shapiro (1992), how stable are the policy
preferences of the American public? When change does occur, under what conditions is it
gradual? When is it likely to be abrupt? Is change capricious?
2. According to Stimson (1999), what
cycles, waves, and trends in public opinion occur over time? Think about the variety of
subjects we have covered so farthe war in Iraq, the environment, the Lewinsky
scandal, etc. Is the trajectory for each over time similar or different? Why?
3. In response to *what* does public
opinion change--to events, experts, politicians, interest groups, the news media, etc?
4. Rally effects are a particularly
interesting form of opinion change. What, exactly, is a rally? According to
Hetherington and Nelson (2003), what makes the rally following 9/11 distinctive? What
explains its duration and (given what we know now) its eventual collapse? What have the
political consequences been?
SOCIAL CAPITAL AND CIVIC PARTICIPATION (Tuesday, March 29)
1. In The Strange Disappearance of Civic America, how does
Putnam in define social capital? From his perspective, why is it so important?
2. Putnams bowling
alone metaphor has become popular in the press. What does it mean?
3. What evidence does Putnam cite when
describing the erosion of social capital in the United States over the last few decades?
What is his prime culprit?
4. Putnams article contains all of
the elements of a good mystery. Are you persuaded by Putnams evidence? Why or why
not?
5. Why, according to Samuelson, is the
Bowling Alone phenomenon bunk? What counter evidence does he cite?
6. On balance, which argument is more
persuasive? For instance, do Putnams data accurately measure participation? Does it
square with other evidence of civic engagement from the same period of time(e.g., the
womens rights movement, Civil Rights, consumer movement, environmental movement-all
of which were grassroots in nature)?
7. Is Putnams baseline fair? For
example, we might say that the 1940s and 1950s were a unique time period. We might ask why
that group was so much more civic in its orientation, not why later groups are not.
8. Does Putnam romanticize the 1950s as a
golden age? Think of the strife, division and racial prejudice of that era.
9. What can the campaigns of Howard Dean
and Barack Obama tell us about social capital? Can the internet create new,
powerful connections between peopledifferent connections (e.g., more global, less
local)but real connections nevertheless?
UNDERSTANDING TRENDS IN VOTER TURNOUT (Thursday, MArch 31)
The decline in voter turnout is, as tomorrows reading
reminds us, the most important, most familiar, most analyzed, and most conjectured
trend in recent American political history. Lets consider two very different
views on the matter:
1. According to Patterson (2002), why
have voters vanished? What reasons does he offer? Are they convincing?
2. What is McDonald and Popkins
(2001) response to this debate? Why do they believe that it is an illusion?
3. How important is this debate? Does low
voter turnout really matter? If so, how?
GETTING OUT THE VOTE (Tuesday, April 5)
In discussing voter turnout last class, we said there were
three possible responses to the issue: A) Do nothing because what seem to be low rates of
voter turnout are in actuality higher. The turnout problem is merely a product
of measuring turnout incorrectly; B) Do nothing because it is not desirable to increase
turnout if that means encouraging the participation of the uneducated and ill-informed;
and C) Do something. In tomorrows class, we will tackle the full range of the
do something option.
1. Marshall Ganz discusses a policy known
as Motor Voter. What is it? According to the author, how well has it worked in
increasing turnout? What are its strengths? What are its weaknesses?
2. Meirick and Wackman come at the
problem from a completely different direction. What is Kids Voting USA? Again, according
to the authors, how well does the program work? Are you convinced by their findings? Why
or why not?
3. In contrast to the first two pieces,
what approach do Gerber and Green take? What strategy for increasing turnout do they
investigate? What methodology do they use? Do you find the evidence they cite compelling?
4. Finally, think about the logic that
underlies each of these proposals. What do they identify as the root cause of the problem?
For instance, in the eyes of Motor Voter proponents, why is turnout low? For those who
support programs like Kids Voting USA, what would they likely believe? How about campaigns
that emphasize canvassing? From their perspective, why dont people vote? Given our
understanding of the issue, are these solutions well suited to the problem? Which is most
likely to work and why?
MODELS OF VOTING BEHAVIOR (Thursday, April 7)
1. In The Two Faces of Issue
Voting, Carmines and Stimson say that there are two theoretically different
and empirically identifiable types. What, exactly, are hard issues? What
are easy issues? In the world of politics today, can you think of any
examples?
2. If issue voting occurs rarely, is that
because of the inherent limitations of the citizen/voter or it is because of
the inadequacies of choice offered by the political system? What role, if any,
might the media play here?
3. If Carmines and Stimson are right when
they suggest that easy-issue voting occurs in waves or surges, how might
political campaigns capitalize? How might they appeal to the easy-issue voter? What risk
is there in doing so?
4. Carmines and Stimson argue that
the study of issue voting is infused with normative considerations. Voters who
cast ballots based on their own personal policy preferences relative to those of party
candidates are often assumed to make decisions that are rational, wise and sophisticated.
What do the authors believe? Should we observe issue voting and infer
sophistication? Why or why not?
5. In The 2000 U.S. Presidential
Election: Can Retrospective Voting be Saved, Fiorina, Abrams and Pope discuss
Gores loss within the context of political science theories that insist that
election outcomes depend on fundamentals, such as peace and prosperity
(remember, Zaller pointed to the same in his article on the Lewinsky scandal). What do
they think is the major cause of Gores defeat? Consider their hypotheses and the
evidence they cite in each case carefully.
6. How might we apply Fiorina, et
als work to the 2004 presidential election? Did Kerry lose to Bush for the same
reasons that Gore lost to Bush?
ELECTIONS AS AN INSTRUMENT OF POPULAR CONTROL (Tuesday, April 12)
In this class we will talk about the political consequences of voter ignorance. As Lau and
Redlawsk point out: The classic texts of democratic theory. assume that for a
democracy to function properly the average citizen should be interested in, pay attention
to, discuss, and actively participate in politics.. Five decades of behavior research in
political science have left no doubt, however, that only a tiny minority of the citizens
in any democracy actually live up to these ideals.
In short, based on so much of what we have read this term,
we know that most citizens are relatively uniformed about politics-they fail the
conditions of Erikson and Tedins rational-activist model, and often
quite miserably-but to what extent does it matter?
Some scholars insist that is inconsequential for two reasons:
A) Poorly informed voters can make efficient use of
relevant cues and cognitive short-cuts;
B) Individual errors tend to cancel out when votes are
aggregated;
In order to explore to these hypotheses, each of
todays reading assignments attempt to compare real and ideal situations: how people
actually vote to how they might vote when fully informed. Notice
first how this is similar to the efforts made by Fishkin and Luskin with
deliberative democracy, then move on to consider these questions:
1. According to Lau and Redlawsk, what
does the term voting correctly mean?
2. Lau and Redlawsk pose an interesting
question: What if people can make reasonably good decisions, most of the time,
without all the motivation and attention and knowledge required by classic theory?
This sounds too good to be true, right? Is it? Quite simply, they write,
human beings have adaptively developed a large series of cognitive heuristics and
shortcuts that allow they to make pretty good judgments most of the
time. This perspective encourages us to judge the outcome (that is, the decision
itself), not just the perceived quality of the process we use to get there. So, what
exactly are these heuristics and shortcuts? How do they work?
3. Describe the experiment the authors
use. How did it work? What was the goal?
4. What do you think of their
experimental design? What are its strengths and weaknesses? Should we ask respondents if
they think they voted correctly? Will respondents be reluctant to admit they
made a mistake? How do the authors adjust for this? What is their second
measure of correct voting?
5. According to the authors
results, what percentage of people voted correctly, both in their experiment
and in their extension of the model to the 1972 through 1988 presidential elections? Are
the numbers high or low? Or, to put it another way, are they high enough?
6. Moving on to Bartels, he says that the
electorate as a whole deviates in significant and politically consequential ways
from the projected behavior of a fully informed electorate. How so?
Other things being equal, who are relatively uninformed voters more likely to support?
7. Why do Bartels results differ
from those of Lau and Redlawsk? Could this be a matter of looking at a glass as half-full
rather than half-empty?
8. Bartels considers the magic of
statistical aggregation at some length. The argument itself is based on Condorcets
theorem (Remember, it proves mathematically that the probability of a correct majority
vote in a group of modestly well-informed individuals may increase substantially as the
size of the group increases). According to Bartels, the practical difficulty with
Condorcets argument is that it only works to the extent that individual errors are
truly random-with an expected value of zero and no correlation across
voters. How likely is this? What conditions during a political campaign are likely
to violate those assumptions?
THE INTERPLAY OF PUBLIC OPINION AND PUBLIC POLICY (Thursday, April 14)
Certainly, public opinion can influence public policy
through the circuitous route offered by elections. We might assume that informed voters
cast ballots for those candidates most proximate to their own policy preferences, and that
representatives act on those preferences sincerely once in office. In reality, of course,
few of us are informed enough to act with much assurance on matters of policy, but as our
previous reading demonstrates, we often find creative ways to vote correctly
much of the time nevertheless.
What, then, are we to make of the second half of our simple democratic theory? How
responsive is government to the preferences of its citizens? These articles tackle both
the empirical and the normative sides of this debate:
1. According to Page and Shapiro, their approach to measuring the
effects of public opinion on policy employs a macrolevel aggregate design
based on congruence. What does this mean? How do they identify their cases?
2. What do they find? In how many cases
was there a congruent change in opinion and policy? What about
noncongruent change, or even no change at all? Are you surprised
by this result?
3. According to the authors, what factors
seem to explainor even predictthe extent of congruence that appears? Does the
type of policy issue matter (e.g., foreign or domestic)? What about the ideological
direction of change? Does that matter?
4. Can you think of any recent examples
of congruent and incongruent changes in policy? Are those cases consistent with the
authors results?
5. As Page and Shapiro point out:
The mere observation of congruence between opinion and policy tells us little, of
course, about which causes which. Under what conditions might a change in government
policy precipitate a change in public attitudes?
6. While Page and Shapiro examine whether
public opinion DOES influence policy, Weisberg questions whether it SHOULD. Does he
believe that polling methodology is scientific enough to provide sound policy
counsel? Is the average citizen wise enough? What do you believe? As Weisberg ask:
Where do we go from here?
MANIPULATING OPINION (Tuesday, April 19)
In this class, we will continue to discuss the reciprocal
link between public opinion and public policy, this time by focusing directly on the role
that politicians play.
1. Syndicated newspaper columnist Maureen
Dowd once wrote that politicians were prisoners of polling. Indeed, with Dick
Morris memoirs of the Clinton years in mind, she said: polling has turned
leaders into followers. There will never such a thing as greatness with a three-to-five
point margin of error. Criticism such as Dowds is commonplace today. There is
a pervasive belief that politicians pander. What does that term mean? How does that word
characterize the relationship between presidents and the polls?
2. According to Michael Barone, how do
politicians use polls? How has this changed over time? Does his brief and somewhat
anecdotal argument confirm or reject the image of the pandering politician?
3. Based on the title of their article,
we know that Jacobs and Shapiros goal is Debunking the Pandering Politician
Myth. Do they agree or disagree with Barone on the extent to which politicians use
polls? Were you impressed or skeptical of the interviews they conducted?
4. According to Jacobs and Shapiro,
the primary purpose of tracking public opinion is not to pander, but to
educate, lead, or otherwise influence public attitudes towards the President and his
policies. From a normative standpoint, contrast this is the pandering
model. Is there a difference between pandering politicians and those who are responsive to
the needs of their constituents? If so, what is it? On the other hand, is there a
difference between presidential leadership and outright manipulation? Where should that
line be drawn?
5. Finally, consider the Luntz memo,
which advises Republicans on how to frame environmental issues to their
advantage. With Carmines and Stimpson in mind, is the attempt to sell the environment as a
hard issue or an easy one? To what extent do you recognize the
language used here in the current policy debate over global warming?
TRUST IN GOVERNMENT (Thursday, April 21)
On the subject of political consequences, it is time to
broaden our scope beyond the relationship between public opinion and public policy on
narrow issues, to an impact on the government system as a whole:
1. What is political trust
and why, according to Hetherington, is it relevant? What, in particular, are the
consequences of low trust?
2. In considering both assigned articles,
what are the most plausible causes for the erosion of political trust in the United
States? For an explanation, should we focus on policy outputs (e.g.,
satisfaction with the policies the government produces), or on a process that
violates our expectations about how the government should make decisions?
3. According to Hibbing and Theiss-Morse,
how do people want government to operate? Are their expectations both rational and
reasonable?
4. Hibbing and Theiss-Morse believe that
process matters. How does this square with other evidence we have considered
this term?
5. As Hibbing and Theiss-Morse observe,
Americans like to complain that the government is out of touch with their needs,
concerns and wants. Is this a fair criticism? Why or why not?
6. What, if anything, can politicians do
to earn the publics trust? As a society, are we simply impossible to please?
7. Should citizens have a healthy
skepticism of their government? Are there benefits to that? |